Can Biological Theories Explain Rolex Watches in Addition to Peacocks Tails?
Join now to read essay Can Biological Theories Explain Rolex Watches in Addition to Peacocks Tails?
Can biological theories explain Rolex watches in addition to peacockās tails?
As humans, we do many things which are not instrumentally useful in an evolutionary sense: we dance, get drunk, create art, listen to music, and dress up in expensive clothing, amongst other things. These exhibitions of āuselessā behaviours cannot be accounted for simply because we are reported to be in an evolutionary disequilibrium (Kirk et al, 2001); even our ancestors exhibited many of these āuselessā behaviours. Aborigines have been painting on rocks for at least 50,000 years, and using make up for twice that long; and painting, jewellery and musical instruments have been around for 35,000 years in Europe alone (Pinker, 2002). Indeed, many animal species engage in analogous activities, especially in the contexts of courtship displays and status contests. But how do we explain these seemingly useless behaviours, seen not only in humans, but across the animal world? Darwin (1871) concluded that natural selection was powerless to account for such apparently pointless splendour, particularly when faced with the evolution of excessively elaborate adornments such as the peacockās tail (Petrie et al., 1991). His solution was the theory of sexual selection, which is the selection for traits which are solely concerned with increasing mating success.
In many animal species, male traits have been subject to stronger sexual selection than female traits. Males of these species tend to compete for females and mate indiscriminately, whereas females are fastidiously choosier. This sex difference is attributably to the fact that males produce large amounts of ācheapā sperm and females produce much larger, more valuable eggs and their parental investment is usually larger (Trivers, 1972). As a result of sexual selection, males of these species have adapted secondary sexual traits that are maladaptive. Zahaviās (1975) handicap hypothesis of sexual selection has increasingly come to dominate discussions about the evolution of these seemingly maladaptive secondary sexual traits (Andersson, 1994). Zahaviās theory predicts that female preferences have evolved for exaggerated sexual ornaments which signal male genetic quality, and these ornaments have coevolved to be larger and more costly. A variety of mechanisms have been proposed as advertisements of genetic calibre (e.g. antlers depicting calcium reserves (Trivers, 1985); bright feather colouration indicating parasite resistance (Hamilton and Zuk, 1982)). Classic experimental studies of this include Anderssonās (1982) long-tailed widow bird, which showed that males with longer tails had significantly higher mating success; and the elaborate display of the song of the European sedge warbler (Catchpole, 1980) which shows that males with the most elaborate songs are the first to acquire mates.
Zahavi (1975, 1977, 1997) used the peacockās long tail to illustrate his theory. The peacockās tail is a handicap in day to day survival, a point that few would dispute. According to his theory, the deleterious structure that is the peacockās tail does, in fact, constitute as a valid indicator that the signalling animal is being honest in its claim of superiority, precisely because the trait is a handicap. By having a large, cumbersome tail that is grown over months where food is scarce, the peacock is advertising that he managed to find food and avoid predators, despite such a burden, proving that he is a high quality mate. The bigger the handicap, the more rigorous test he has passed.
But how can we extend Zahaviās theory to explain the useless behaviour exhibited by humans cross-culturally and throughout history? Zahaviās handicap theory shows us that useless or, more importantly, costly things can be paradoxically highly useful for a certain purpose: evaluating the assets of the bearer. This point was first made by Thornstein Veblen (1899) in his Theory of the Leisure Class where he wrote that the psychology of taste is driven by three āpecuniary canonsā: conspicuous consumption, conspicuous leisure and conspicuous waste. Conspicuous consumption and abstinence from work are the two ways the leisure class can distinguish itself from the labour class, with conspicuous waste being the main feature. Leisure is a waste of time and conspicuous consumption is a waste of money so Veblen came to the conclusion that all this waste is, in fact, a measure of social status. In order to distinguish themselves from others, people need to consume and advertise to display their wealth. This is an enduring battle for prestige where people who show off expensive jewels, Rolex watches, sports cars or works of art gain status because the signal cannot be faked. Miller (1999) called this the Sennheiser Effect; where top of the range products are the equivalent peacockās tails of humans. Their price is a benefit, not