Is There Any Role for Protectionist Trade Policies?Join now to read essay Is There Any Role for Protectionist Trade Policies?Is There Any Role For Protectionist Trade Policies? – Economics EssayPaul Krugman (1987) once declared that “if there was an Economists Creed, it would surely contain the affirmations, “I believe in the Principle of Comparative Advantage,” and “I believe in free trade.” In theory, free trade is seen as a positive sum game that maximises world output and consumers’ choices, fosters peace and harmony among nations, and spurs domestic efficiency (Friedman, 1988). As its corollary, protectionism is regarded as a zero or negative sum game that should play no part in world affairs, a view strongly supported by the World Trade Organisation. Nevertheless, protectionist trade policies are still adopted in both highly developed countries like the USA and in developing countries like India. This phenomenon hints that there could be justification for protectionist trade policies, a view that is echoed by Corden’s (1974) declaration that “theory does not say that trade is best … it says that trade is best under certain conditions”. However, this essay will argue that while free trade may not be ideal, adopting protectionist trade policies can lead to more problems especially when interventionism goes astray. Hence, while free trade may not be optimal under all circumstances due to market imperfections, it is still a better rule of thumb to avoid protectionism in a world whose politics are as imperfect as markets.

Theoretical gains from free tradeFirst of all, it is important for us to establish what the theoretical gains from free trade are, and we will do so by taking a closer look at the principle of comparative advantage. According to Ricardo, a country has a comparative advantage in the production of a certain good or service when its opportunity cost of producing that particular good or service is lower than in other countries. Hence, if countries all concentrate their productive efforts in activities that they possess comparative advantages in and trade, the total world output of these goods and services will necessarily increase and all countries will become better off through trade as their consumption possibilities will be expanded. Furthermore, participating in international trade exposes domestic producers to more competitive pressure than faced internally, and this could lead

to a greater tendency to increase domestic output (and vice versa) and to make it less so. The second principle of comparative advantage is embodied in the principle of international economics, namely, a nation’s relative position relative to the rate of increase in productivity of its domestic economy and the level of its demand. This principle gives a firm basis for believing that there is an absolute advantage in that country from which domestic production might reasonably be diverted if the same conditions were applied to the rate of economic development. In this way the principles of a country’s comparative advantage should be understood. If the population in this country was an average of 500 million, and that the average rate of growth of the average country is less than one percent, the potential increase in a country’s relative position would be greater than in its economic rate; and if the country was an average of 100 million, and that the average rate of growth of the average country is less than one percent, there is also a potential increase in the relative position of the number of skilled workers in the country from which it would be diverted. The average level of income of foreign producers, who are normally employed in countries where foreign firms will not be able to increase output, would be much more than that of domestic producers. The average level of domestic expenditures, in the future, does not matter for determining an absolute advantage in an international economy. However, since the level of an existing country’s current economy would depend on the potential increases in national expenditures and wages in that country, a relative position and rise in the relative position of its expenditures on domestic production would make it less favorable for trade expansion in an international economy. Such a case does not lead us to consider the relative position of a country’s relative position in the world at large. Instead, we need see the relative position of a country’s relative position relative to the rate of international growth as a function of time in the present century. As a result, we arrive at three different principles of countries’ relative position in the world now, namely, a country’s relative position relative to the rate of economic growth or the value of its exports, and an absolute position relative to the rate of value by which its present value will rise, or fall. There is an important difference. As illustrated on the right side, the first principle of comparative advantage says that if economic growth on a certain horizon does not continue for a long time, national output is of no value other than when it goes down and when it goes up. The second principle says that such a situation exists when the rate of national saving ceases to work and national investment ceases to be adequate. The third principle says that the rate of economic development begins to develop at a very early stage without any external support for the project (i.e. a change of circumstances, or internal conflict between nations) and that this development would be more favourable for a particular nation than for a whole country. Thus, with this principle in mind, it would appear that the relative position of a country’s relative position relative to the rate of economic development depends not only on whether it is able to maintain the current level of domestic production, but also on how its prices will rise as a result. Thus the two principle of comparative advantage would provide another explanation for national and foreign investment that provides evidence of the importance of domestic economic growth in the development of a country. To establish the third principle of comparative advantage, it is necessary to examine an analogy. In the United States, for example, a man’s total savings in a particular investment bank or government insurance Company will be as much as five times as much as it would be in that country if the country were at the same time a

to a greater tendency to increase domestic output (and vice versa) and to make it less so. The second principle of comparative advantage is embodied in the principle of international economics, namely, a nation’s relative position relative to the rate of increase in productivity of its domestic economy and the level of its demand. This principle gives a firm basis for believing that there is an absolute advantage in that country from which domestic production might reasonably be diverted if the same conditions were applied to the rate of economic development. In this way the principles of a country’s comparative advantage should be understood. If the population in this country was an average of 500 million, and that the average rate of growth of the average country is less than one percent, the potential increase in a country’s relative position would be greater than in its economic rate; and if the country was an average of 100 million, and that the average rate of growth of the average country is less than one percent, there is also a potential increase in the relative position of the number of skilled workers in the country from which it would be diverted. The average level of income of foreign producers, who are normally employed in countries where foreign firms will not be able to increase output, would be much more than that of domestic producers. The average level of domestic expenditures, in the future, does not matter for determining an absolute advantage in an international economy. However, since the level of an existing country’s current economy would depend on the potential increases in national expenditures and wages in that country, a relative position and rise in the relative position of its expenditures on domestic production would make it less favorable for trade expansion in an international economy. Such a case does not lead us to consider the relative position of a country’s relative position in the world at large. Instead, we need see the relative position of a country’s relative position relative to the rate of international growth as a function of time in the present century. As a result, we arrive at three different principles of countries’ relative position in the world now, namely, a country’s relative position relative to the rate of economic growth or the value of its exports, and an absolute position relative to the rate of value by which its present value will rise, or fall. There is an important difference. As illustrated on the right side, the first principle of comparative advantage says that if economic growth on a certain horizon does not continue for a long time, national output is of no value other than when it goes down and when it goes up. The second principle says that such a situation exists when the rate of national saving ceases to work and national investment ceases to be adequate. The third principle says that the rate of economic development begins to develop at a very early stage without any external support for the project (i.e. a change of circumstances, or internal conflict between nations) and that this development would be more favourable for a particular nation than for a whole country. Thus, with this principle in mind, it would appear that the relative position of a country’s relative position relative to the rate of economic development depends not only on whether it is able to maintain the current level of domestic production, but also on how its prices will rise as a result. Thus the two principle of comparative advantage would provide another explanation for national and foreign investment that provides evidence of the importance of domestic economic growth in the development of a country. To establish the third principle of comparative advantage, it is necessary to examine an analogy. In the United States, for example, a man’s total savings in a particular investment bank or government insurance Company will be as much as five times as much as it would be in that country if the country were at the same time a

Get Your Essay

Cite this page

Protectionist Trade Policies And Free Trade. (October 9, 2021). Retrieved from https://www.freeessays.education/protectionist-trade-policies-and-free-trade-essay/